LATEX

LATEX

Friday, September 30, 2016

Value & Capital, Note to Chapter VIII -- CONVENTIONAL OR RIGID PRICES

Chapter VIII concludes with a note that examines what happens when some price is fixed.  Figure 22 shows supply and demand curves (S and D) for a single commodity, with the prices of all other commodities assumed to be fixed.  If the price of this particular commodity were not fixed, then it would move to the level represented by the intersection of the supply and demand curves.


If the price were fixed at a higher level (say at the level OL), then the demand curve implies that only a quantity ON would be sold, even though the supply curve implies that sellers would be willing to sell a quantity LT.  (Note that, by construction, the quantities ON, LP, and MQ are all equal.)  The note then argues that
The situation is therefore identical with that which would have arisen if a price OL had been fixed for buyers only, a price OM for sellers only, the difference between those prices being handed over as a bonus to those sellers who actually do make sales.  (Alternatively, we may suppose that a tax equal to LM per unit is laid upon the commodity, and the proceeds of that tax handed over to the sellers.  A process made familiar to us by the [UK] Ministry of Agriculture!)
The text points out that this construction retains an equilibrium in which supply equals demand, but "we have to sacrifice the rule that there is only one price in the market."  The real price is the assumed fixed price, and the text introduces the term "shadow price" to represent the price determined by equilibrium conditions.  In this context, the shadow price is OM.  The text notes that this shadow price is not the price that the sellers actually receive, so there is no income effect associated with it, but it does govern substitution effects on the supply side.

The text then assumes that demand for the commodity increases (represented by a change in the demand curve from D to D').  If the price remains fixed at OL, the amount bought will increase from LP to LP', and the shadow price will increase from OM to OM'.  The text points out the significance of the fact that the "supply will increase in just the same way (apart from the income effect) as if the actual price had increased from OM to OM'.  That is why the shadow price is important."  Any reactions in the markets for other commodities that are caused by changes in the supply of this commodity "will proceed as if there had been a real change in price; it is only is only reactions on the demand side which are cut off by the price-fixation."

Finally, the text considers an example in which there is "a minimum price for wheat, combined with jut sufficient restriction of supply to make the minimum price effective."  If there is an increase in demand, our model above shows that even though the fixed price doesn't change, there should be an increase in supply (as described by the supply curve).  Because this expansion in supply may come at the expense of some other crops (i.e. lower quantities of these other crops may be supplied), the prices of these other crops may rise, just as if the price of wheat had risen.

The note concludes that "The significance of this proposition (which is equally valid for maximum prices, when all term are reversed) is self-evident.  Price control can damp down a general rise in prices; but, unless it is absolutely complete, it cannot prevent it altogether."


Friday, September 16, 2016

Value & Capital, CHAPTER VIII, Section 7

This section explores in further detail some of the results of preceding sections by examining the role of "the standard commodity" (and considering what happens in the case where this is money).

Previous sections assumed an increase in the supply of factor A or in the demand for product X and examined the effects on the prices of other commodities, depending on whether these other commodities are substitutes or complements of the given product or factor.  The discussion in the previous section implicitly assumed that
... the amount of A offered at given prices increased, and the suppliers demanded nothing but some of the standard commodity in exchange.  If the standard commodity is money, this implies that they hoard all the income which they derive from the new units they supply.  Similarly, in [Section 5 of this chapter] it is implicitly assumed that the new demand is demand in terms of the standard commodity; so that if the standard commodity is money, the new demand comes from dishoarding, not from economizing on other goods.
If instead of making this implicit assumption we were to assume that the changes mentioned above were accompanied by changes in the demands for products, these latter changes would "produce an effect on general prices which goes in the opposite direction from the primary effect."  In particular, suppose that along with the increased supply of factor A there is an increased demand for products. The text argues that "prices in general" will only decrease if there is hoarding.  In other words, unless suppliers keep all their additional proceeds as money, they will spend some of it on products, which will tend to increase prices.  Conversely, suppose that along with the increased demand for product X there is a decreased demand for other products. Unless the increased demand for X comes from some dishoarding, all of the increased demand must be paid for through reduced spending for other products, thus decreasing their prices.

The discussion in the text also makes reference to the possible difficulties of calculating the net effect on prices of a combination of increased supply of a factor and increased demand for certain commodities.  Sometimes this can be simplified by choosing a representative consumption good as the standard commodity.  In other cases, there are obstacles to using this sort of device.  If there are any prices in the system that are fixed in terms of money, "severe intellectual contortions are needed" unless we choose money as the standard commodity.